Annex A of the draft agreement, dealing with agriculture, makes clear how much the EU has got in return, creating an extremely imbalanced framework for establishing modalities in agriculture and damaging in the process the interests of developing countries and agricultural exporters. The draft declares that the Annex details the elements that ''offer the additional precision required at this stage of the negotiations'' in pursuit of the objective of establishing ''a fair and market-oriented trading system through a process of fundamental reform''. But it is quick to correct itself and states that ''the final balance will be found only at the conclusion of these subsequent negotiations and within the Single Undertaking.''

This formulation clearly uses the Single Undertaking notion to provide for the possibility of a compromise. In the language of the draft, too much precision is not possible in the current stage, especially given the need for a quick consensus. Since the single undertaking idea requires countries to take all or nothing, they are expected to make compromises, accepting less in some areas and gaining more in others. Countries are expected to give and take in the agricultural area, for example, in lieu of offers and demands in other spheres, so that the final balance remains tentative. The underlying assumption is that special interests of individual countries vary enough to allow for a consensus to emerge through the Single Undertaking route.

It should be obvious that a framework of this kind should be relatively flexible in all areas, and equally so, in order to provide space for compromise. This, however, is not the case. In agriculture the minimum bounds of a possible compromise in terms of reduced support by the developed countries has been fixed at a relatively high level, reducing the space for negotiation. In other areas, however, the floor to which countries can be expected to proceed has either been made flexible (as in the case of non-agricultural market access or special and differential treatment for developing countries) or rendered non-existent.

This bias becomes clear in the discussions on the ‘three pillars’ of domestic support, export competition and market access. The massive domestic support for agriculture in the US, EU and Japan that adversely affects global prices of agricultural commodities as well as the access of developing country exporters to developed country markets is now well known. According to the OECD Secretariat, the level of support provided to agricultural producers expressed as the monetary value of transfers from consumers and budgetary payments to producers (the Producer Support Estimate or PSE) amounted to $230 billion in 2002 and $257 billion in 2003. This was equal to a third of the current OECD gross farm receipts. Reacting to these (or even higher) levels of support, countries have been demanding substantial reductions overall domestic support.

What the draft framework does is to divert attention from the need to do adopt such policies as part of the effort to move towards a fair trading system and focus on the quantum of support which is being provided under heads other than the Green Box. The issue in focus is not the principle or the nature but the quantum of support. As a result there are three different measures of support that are recognised as acceptable and discussed. These are the aggregate measure of support (AMS), which covers only those payments made through means that are expressly considered trade-distorting; the de minimis level of support, which permits all countries to retain some degree of support through trade-distorting measures independent of their level of AMS in the benchmark year; and third the total trade-distorting support, which includes support being provided through these means as well as through the adoption of Blue Box measures.

This leads up to a set of recommendations. The first is the need for substantial and effective reduction in the overall level of trade distorting support, defined as the sum total of these three.

The second is the adoption of a tiered formula for reduction in domestic support: countries with higher levels of allowed support will be expected to make deeper cuts. This tiered reduction approach will also be followed for reduction of the final bound level of aggregate support or total possible AMS, and product specific caps would be specified at their average levels during an agreed historical period, to prevent transfer of unchanged domestic support between categories.

The third is the reduction of the permissible de minimis level.

The fourth is a cap on the level of Blue Box support as a percentage of the average value of agricultural production. This implies the retention of the Blue Box which was to be phased out by 2004, as a viable means of agricultural reform. There is no talk of phasing out these measures even by the end of the Doha Round, if such a Round were to begin. What is more, the draft calls for some flexibility to ensure that members providing a high share of trade distorting support through Blue Box measures would not have to make disproportionate cuts.

Finally, even though there is mention of the need to review Green Box measures to ensure that they have no, ''or at most minimal'', trade distorting effects, it has been made clear that the basic concepts, principles and effectiveness of the Green Box should remain.

The concessions offered in return for the right to protect are in the area of export subsidies for agriculture that are to be phased out. Since this affects the EU disproportionately, given the its current use of such measures, an effort is made to elicit parallel commitments form other countries. There is to be a parallel elimination of trade distorting elements of export credits and export credit guarantees (that are to be on commercial terms), of practices adopted by State Trading Enterprises in export sales, and of food aid that can used as a mechanism of surplus disposal. But even here, the schedule for implementing new obligations, commitments and disciplines ''will take into account the need for coherence with internal reform steps of Members''. While concerns of the developed are consistently thus addressed, the only special concession being provided to developing countries in this area is a longer implementation period.

Even in the area of market access there is to be single approach for developed and developing countries, with differentiation based only on the current level of tariffs using a tiered tariff reduction formula in which there would be deeper cuts in the case of higher tariffs. While LDCs are to be exempted from a contribution, special and differential treatment for developing countries is recognised as ''an integral part of all elements'' but left unspecified.

Finally, a reference to ''flexibilities'' for sensitive products, which has pleased Japan, have been made, but concessions to developing countries for Special Products impinging on issues of rural development, livelihood security and food security is mentioned but left undefined and their accommodation left to the ''post-Framework stage''

In sum, the concern in the agricultural area during the framework stage has been to take on board the sensitivities of the developed countries, particularly the European Union, while postponing any special specification relating to the developing countries. But even this does not seem to ensure full support from within the developed country camp. French President Jacques Chirac has declared that the draft framework is "unacceptable", and Prime Minister Jean-Pierre Raffarin has warned the European Commission that "France cannot give its agreement to a negotiation concluded on this basis." Resentment about the role played by French Commissioner Lamy runs high, and he is unlikely to get official backing either for continuing in the Commission or finding a slot in other international institutions. But the European Union as a group has implicitly endorsed the draft, which is being pushed because France does not have a veto.

Having partially cleared the developed-country stumbling block, the effort of the developed countries seems to be to split the developing country camp so as to prevent any attempt by them to unite and stall the Doha round. Interestingly, on July 13, before the release of the draft framework, trade officials from the US, the European Union, Brazil and India, issued a statement urging ministers of the Group of 90 (G90) developing countries meeting in Mauritius, to back the effort to arrive at a framework agreement by the end of July. The ability to win support from India and Brazil can be attributed to efforts by these countries to use a new round to win concessions in areas relevant to them, such as cross-border supply of services in the case of India. This combined plea of two leading developing countries, in collaboration with the developed countries, put pressure on the G90 to dilute some of its demands including the demand to separately negotiate, independent of the overall negotiations on agriculture, American subsidies on cotton that affect the livelihoods of their peasantry extremely adversely. The draft framework states that the cotton question ''will be addressed ambitiously and expeditiously as an integral part of the negotiations''. It deserves a mention, in the WTO’s view, but not special treatment.

Earlier in May, Pascal Lamy made a controversial effort to drive a wedge into the developing country camp, by proposing that weak and vulnerable countries, which are part of G90, should be offered the benefits of a new round ''for free'', by exempting them from making any liberalisation commitments. A similar proposal has come from the EU, which calls for channelling the benefits of its preferential trade scheme more to the poorest countries, giving them advantages relative to larger developing countries like China and India that are now the major beneficiaries of the preferential trading scheme. The intention is clearly to divide sections of developing countries and weaken their opposition to the specific form in which the developed country camp wants to push ahead with the Doha Round.

Whether such tactics would work and we would see a replay of the Uruguay Round drama remains to be seen. But as of now the only hope that remains is that the patently unequal and biased framework draft makes it impossible for developing countries to succumb to a strategy that relies on power rather than reason to realise imperial ambitions dressed in the rhetoric of economic rationality.

<< Previous Page | 1 | 2 |

 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2004